Tuesday 24 March 2015

Will the merger between BT and EE generate shareholder value?

The basic motivation of a merger should be to add value to a company, thereby enhancing shareholder wealth. That said, this is not always the case. There is much debate regarding the success of mergers, with some claiming the majority destroy shareholder value. With this in mind, the recent announcement of BT’s takeover of EE provided an interesting read (Roland & Williams, 2015; Thomas, 2015; Williams, 2015; & Hargreaves Lansdown, 2015); would this takeover succumb to the factors that have previously rendered other mergers disasters? Or would, despite the odds stacked against the success of mergers, it realise the benefits it anticipates from the merger?

A merger is typically classed as a friendly, negotiated deal. So far, the BT-EE merger has been friendly, although approval is still required from shareholders. There are 3 different types of mergers; horizontal, vertical and conglomerate. The BT-EE merger takes the form of a horizontal merger as the two firms are involved in similar business activity. The horizontal nature of the merger means competition clearance is required from the UK Competition and Markets Authority. A vertical merger is a situation in which firms from different stages of the supply chain merge. Businesses in completely separate industries that unite is known as a conglomerate merger, although these are quite rare in the UK.

There are various different motives associated with mergers being undertaken.  The neoclassical theory proposes that managers will only engage in takeover activity if it leads to the creation of shareholder wealth. This is likely to be the case with the BT-EE merger, and most horizontal mergers, as there are various potential synergies from the deal which have the ability to maximise shareholder wealth. Economies of scale play a large role in this, as a larger sized firm may lead to lower costs through the utilisation of resources. BT forecast a large cost saving off the back of the merger, with an expected £360m saved on operating costs and capital expenditure every year by the fourth full year following the transaction. This has a net present value of around £3.5bn before integration costs, falling to £3bn after these costs are taken into account. Spreading costs over an increased range of products creates economies of scale. As BT is aiming for a full union of mobile and fixed telecoms, this is likely to result in new products and services to spread their costs and generate further revenue. Revenue synergies from the wider range of products are expected to amount to a net present value of £1.6bn.

Managerial synergy could also have played a role in the merger, as BT clearly believes they can run EE better than it is currently being run. Inefficient managers can be replaced and expert skills transferred between both companies. This can be seen in the takeover agreement between the two firms, which states Deutsche Telekom, joint owner of EE, have the right to appoint a director to the BT board. The two companies say this creates a platform for them to work together, sharing best practice in the process. These motives behind the BT-EE merger suggest it will generate value for shareholders. BT seems focused on creating synergies, including higher revenues and lower costs, as well as working with EE. At first glance, there does not appear to be any managerial motives, such as higher salaries and remuneration packages, behind the deal.

An alternative argument suggests managers own personal interests could be the motivations behind mergers. This stems from agency theory, which suggests a difference in goals between managers and shareholders may cause managers to prioritise their own needs as opposed to shareholder wealth maximisation. Factors including increased remuneration and power may encourage such behaviour. Evidence has found managers are rewarded off the back of mergers even if they turn out to be unsuccessful. Alternatively, the manager could suffer from 'hubris', leading them to overestimate their abilities to run the merger on completion. This stems from overconfidence. It may be the case that the managers at BT simply wanted to 'enhance their CV' by running a much larger, more dominant company. If this proves to be the case, it is unlikely to merger will be successful in generating shareholder value.

The financing of mergers is most frequently made up of either cash or shares. BT is paying £12.5bn for EE; however, the sellers, Deutsche Telekom and Orange, are receiving most of this in stock. Deutsche Telekom will have a 12% stake in BT, and Orange will have a 4% stake. A major advantage of this is that tax can be avoided for the time being. It also reduces the amount of cash BT must provide as part of the deal.  However, to achieve this BT raised £1bn from the sale of 2.2 million new shares at 455p. This will dilute the position of existing shareholders; not necessarily a popular decision. Despite this, BT will still have to make use of debt to fund the rest of the takeover, and take on EE’s existing debt of £2.1bn. This will affect BT's capital structure as gearing would be increased; the company should ensure this would not increase financial distress costs too dramatically as this may destroy shareholder wealth. Cash may be preferred by the target as it carries a certainty of worth, however, this may be subject to taxation. Despite the limitations associated with each financing method, it appears to me that BT has funded the merger in a way that best suits the company. This has allowed them to strengthen their abilities and improve their free cash flow.

Despite potential synergies and opportunity to maximise shareholder wealth, there has been widespread criticism of mergers. Grubb & Lamb (2000) claimed that only 20% of all mergers succeed; hardly enticing odds for shareholders facing the prospect of a merger. Evidence regarding whether bidding firms generate value through mergers is somewhat ambiguous. Jenson & Ruback (1983) showed share price increased by 4% on average following a successful bid, and dropped 1% following an unsuccessful bid. The BT-EE merger certainly follows this proposal, with BT experiencing a 4.5% increase in share price on the day the final terms of the merger were announced. Shares reached their highest point in 14 years, showing the positive reaction from the marketplace. However, it remains to be see whether this success will continue once the merger is undertaken. Alternative studies have found successful mergers reduce the wealth of bidding firms shareholders (Firth, 1980). This implies the motivations behind the takeover may play a role in determining whether the merger is successful; it will create shareholder wealth if shareholders interests were prioritised when creating the deal. Target firms seem to benefit from mergers more; Jenson & Ruback (1983) found shares increased by 30% upon successful bids, dropping 3% for any unsuccessful bids. This led some to claim the increase in wealth of target shareholders is at the expense of bidding shareholders

The forecasts provided by BT of the synergies expected from the deal seem well thought out. They recognise the cost of integration and time required to make the merger a success, stating benefits will be realised in the fourth full year from the transaction. The marketplace reacted well upon the announcement of the merger and I believe this signals that the deal has the potential to generate shareholder wealth. Having said that, the merger still requires approval from shareholders and clearance from UK authorities, showing it is still in its early days. On the basis of this, I am inclined to refrain from full judgement of the merger, at least for now. Therefore, it remains to be seen whether the BT-EE merger will relish in the predicted success, generating value for shareholders, or fall foul to the curse of mergers falling flat and destroying shareholder value.


References

Arnold, G. (2013). Corporate Financial Management. (5th ed.), Harlow: Pearson Education.

Hargreaves Lansdown. (2015). BT Group plc. Retrieved 24 March 2015, from http://www.hl.co.uk/shares/shares-search-results/b/bt-group-plc-ordinary-5p/share-research

Jensen, M. & Ruback, R. (1983). The market for corporate control: The scientific evidence, Journal of Financial Economics, 11(1-4), 5-50. doi: 10.1016/0304-405X(83)90004-1

Firth, M. (1980). Takeovers, Shareholders Returns, and the Theory of the Firm, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94(2), 235-260. Retrieved from JSTOR http://www.jstor.org/

Roland, D. & Williams, C. (2015). BT unveils £1bn share placing to help fund EE takeover. Retrieved 23 March 2015, from http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/newsbysector/mediatechnologyandtelecoms/telecoms/11407624/BT-unveils-1bn-share-placing-to-help-fund-EE-takeover.html

Roll, R. (1986). The Hubris Hypothesis of Corporate Takeovers, The Journal of Business, 59(2), 197-216. Retrieved from JSTOR http://www.jstor.org/

Thomas, D. (2015). BT shares surge as £12.5bn takeover of EE is finalised. Retrieved 23 March 2015, from http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/4a88704e-ae20-11e4-8188-00144feab7de.html#axzz3VEtETs3w

Thomas, D. & Massoudi, A. (2015). BT seals the £12.5bn deal to buy EE. Retrieved 23 March 2015, from http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/9a74a0ec-ac6c-11e4-9aaa-00144feab7de.html#axzz3VEtETs3w

Watson, D. & Head, A. (2013). Corporate Finance: principles and practices. (6th ed.), Harlow: Pearson Education.
Williams, C. (2015). BT begins 48-hour ‘£17bn’ spending binge with EE takeover. Retrieved 23 March 2015, from http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/newsbysector/mediatechnologyandtelecoms/telecoms/11394138/BT-begins-48-hour-17bn-spending-binge-with-EE-takeover.html